|
KNOWLEDGE BASED DEVELOPMENT IN MEXICO: IS THERE A ROLE FOR
THE UNIVERSITY?
Norma
Vite León
Correo-e: [email protected]
Instituto de Investigaciones Sociales, UNAM.
Resumen
Ahora más que nunca, se espera que las universidades contribuyan
al avance económico de un país produciendo conocimiento
tecnológico. Actualmente, la idea de que existe una relación
causal desde la investigación que se realiza en las universidades
a la innovación comercial y el desarrollo regional, es generalmente
aceptada. El propósito de este artículo es examinar los
esfuerzos que se han realizado para estimular la colaboración
universidad-industria en el contexto de la economía mexicana,
criticar sus resultados, y en el contexto de países desarrollados
y en vías de desarrollo, analizar diferentes alternativas. La
finalidad es estimular el debate y reconsiderar la generalmente aceptada,
aunque poco explorada, conceptualización de la universidad como
un "motor" del desarrollo económico.
Palabras clave: Universidad,
vinculación, empresa, políticas
públicas.
Abstract
It is generally assumed that
there is a linear pathway from university investigation to commercial
innovation to regional
development and widening
networks of innovation. The purpose of this paper is to examine efforts
that have been made to stimulate university-industry collaboration in
the context of the mexican economy, to critique their results, and, in
the context of experiences in both developed and developing countries,
to review alternative perspectives. It is hoped that this framework will
stimulate researchers and policy makers to reconsider their vigorous
but largely unexamined drive to conceptualize the university as the "engine" of
economic development and to consider a more nuance role for the university
in this process.
Key words: Pathway investigation, university,
technological innovation.
Technological knowledge and
innovation are more and more conceptualized as the machinery that drives
economic development.
As evidence of the
economic and social benefits that stem from exploitation of new scientific
and technological knowledge accrues, the future well-being of industrialized
societies is increasingly seen as dependent upon knowledge and innovation
(Neef, Sesfeld, & Cefola, 1998; Nelson, 1996; Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD), 1997a, 1999; World Bank, 1999). The
emphasis on the role of knowledge in global competitiveness for advanced
economies has had a tremendous impact on the way that governments, researchers,
and international development institutions have conceived the development
process in developing economies. The World Bank, for example, has proposed
to view the problems of development from "a knowledge perspective",
according to which gaps in knowledge differentiate between developed
and developing economies. This perspective emphasizes two interrelated
mechanisms for economic development, both of which involve "catching
up" by closing knowledge gaps. The first mechanism consists of the
opening of channels for externally generated knowledge to flow to local
industries in developing countries, thus enabling them to "catch
up" through the informed selection, absorption, and adaptation of
imported technology. The second relates to the eventual generation of
indigenous knowledge through the strengthening of domestic research and
development (R&D) capabilities (World Bank, 1999).
In this context, public interest in the university as the primary source
of new skills, knowledge and ideas has placed it in the role of something
akin to the fuel that drives the "engine" of development (Kodama & Branscomb,
1999). One result has been an intense drive by policy makers to actively
encourage collaborative research relationships between universities and
industry in developing nations, including Mexico. The impetus behind
this drive rests on two related assumptions. First, it is assumed that
there is a linear pathway from university investigation to commercial
innovation, to regional development and widening networks of innovation
(e.g., Florida & Cohen, 1999). Secondly, it is assumed that if institutional
structures and relationships in developing nations, such as Mexico, can
be transformed to replicate those observed in advanced industrialized
nations, innovation and expanding innovatory networks will necessarily
follow.
Pathways of development, however, are not necessarily linear, and the
complexities of university-industry relations have not been fully understood,
even in industrialized countries. Furthermore, a key difference between
advanced industrialized nations and economic systems in the developing
world is that the latter depend heavily on the ability to absorb and
disseminate knowledge generated abroad. An important question in this
context involves the degree to which university-industry linkages in
developing economies like that of Mexico can realistically be expected
to enhance the competitive performance of domestic industry. The answer
to this question requires a deeper level of theoretical understanding
of these processes than we have now. Perhaps the most problematic aspect
of this drive to stimulate university-industry collaboration in developing
economies, however, has been the failure to consider developmental pathways
through which these relationships typically develop and the manner in
which country- or culture-specific infrastructures enhance or limit these
mechanisms.
The central argument of this paper is that a critical examination of
the potential role of university-industry research linkages must include
consideration of development as a dynamic rather than a static entity
and must give thought to how specific cultural and institutional factors
influence the industrial development process. The purpose is to examine
efforts thathave been made to stimulate these relationships, to critique
their results, and, in the context of experiences in both developed and
developing countries, to review alternative perspectives. It is hoped
that this framework will stimulate researchers and policy makers to reconsider
their vigorous but largely unexamined drive to conceptualize the university
as the "engine" of economic development and to consider a more
nuanced role for the university in this process.
The role of the university in a knowledge-based economy
The crucial role of knowledge in modern society has been championed by
a spectrum of academic, business, and policy sources. Terms such as
the knowledge-based economy, the learning economy and more generally
the knowledge-based society are commonly used in disciplines such as
economics, history, and sociology, to describe advanced economies in
which the production of goods and services is becoming increasingly
knowledge-intensive via the better use of existing stocks of scientific
knowledge, the diffusion of advanced equipment, and the managing of
an increasingly complex knowledge base related to productive activities
(Archibugi & Lundvall, 2001; Geuna, 1999; Lundvall, 1992; OECD,
1996, 1997; Rubenson & Schuetze, 2000).
Research in more advanced economies, particularly in member countries
of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD),
has provided evidence supporting the idea that R&D activities drive
the economic success and competitiveness of innovative firms on both
national and international levels (OECD, 1999). In the last decade, as
these economies have moved from science policy with broad social objectives
towards an innovation policy more narrowly focused on impacting economic
performance, the connection between innovation and economic policies
aimed at encouraging growth have become stronger and more direct (Lundvall,
2001; OECD, 1997a, 1999).
Now more than ever, universities are expected to contribute to the development
of individuals who are prepared to acquire, transform and generate new
technologies. Nelson (1993), for example, argues that "... universities
play an extremely important role in technical advance, not only as places
where industrial scientists and engineers are trained, but as the sources
of research finding and techniques of considerable relevance to technical
advance in industry" (p. 11).
Furthermore, in addition to the traditional role of universities in disseminating
knowledge through publications for later application in industry, universities
are increasingly expected to contribute directly to the creation of new
products and services (Ludvall 2002).
The role of the university
in Mexico
New patterns of university-industry collaboration have led to revised
expectations for higher educational systems in developing countries.
Traditionally, the role of Mexican universities in industry has been
focused almost exclusively on the development of manpower. In Mexico,
the generally poor innovation performance by Mexican industry has been
perceived as a constraint on global competitiveness (CONACyT 1995, 2001;
OECD, 1997b; World Bank, 1994). As a result, national policy makers and
international development organizations have sought to bring about a
more direct collaboration between Mexican universities and Mexican industry
in order to foment the development of technological capabilities (Casas,
1997; CONACyT, 1995, 2002; OECD, 1997b). Modeled on university-industry
relationships in knowledge-based economies, such as the United States
and the United Kingdom, the expectation seems to be that if Mexican universities,
motivated by higher education reforms and thedemands of economic globalization,
produce knowledge relevant for industry, they will naturally move to
play a more central role in industrial development, similar to the experience
of advanced economies. According to the World Bank (2000):
The largest role for universities is in carrying out the initial research,
but subsequent product development and distribution often result in a
fruitful interplay between universities in industry. In many developed
countries an increasing number of companies are spinning off from universities,
a process that happens when researchers are encouraged to look for commercial
applications of their work (pp. 80-81).
Morote and Yeager (2000) have argued that the future of the university
in Mexico depends on the ability of universities to incorporate themselves
into the development strategy of the country: "Universities, if
they are to survive and prosper, will have to continue their efforts
to develop linkages with business and industry. It will be through such
changes that universities can become an important element in Mexico's
sustainable economic development" (p. 220).
Results from efforts to stimulate university-industry collaboration in
the development process in Mexico, however, have been generally disappointing.
Formal collaboration aimed at the improvement or development of new products
or processes has been scant, and highly trained manpower that is potentially
capable of conducting research and development activities remains heavily
concentrated in governmental and academic jobs (Casas, 2001; Casas, de
Gortari, & Luna, 2000; Casas & Luna 1997; Economic Commission
for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC), 2001).
The few existing studies that have examined these problems have attempted
to identify internal causes for the low intensity of industry-university
relationships, focusing on local phenomena, including the bureaucratic
nature of Mexican universities, their scant devotion of resources to
research and development activities, and the lack of coordination policy
initiatives that seek to stimulate collaboration (Castaños-Lomnitz,
Didriksson & Newson, 1998; National Science Foundation (NSF), 2000;
Valenti, Varela & Castillo, 2000; World Bank 2000). These analyses
have generally failed to consider potential differences in pathways to
development, ignoring, for instance, the response of Mexican firms to
trade liberalization, market deregulation, and privatization of economic
activities. As a result of these processes, Mexican firms are increasingly
relying on external agents as sources of technical progress. Consequently,
the demand from the Mexican productive sector for local engineering,
highly-skilled manpower, and technological capabilities is shrinking
(Katz 2001). None of the analyses of university-industry group effort
has questioned the model of a linear pathway to development through the
promulgation of university-industry partnership.
The encouragement
of university-industry linkages
In the last two decades, the Mexican government has attempted to support
the development of technological capabilities of firms by encouraging
interaction with public universities and research centers (Casas & Luna,
1997; CONACyT, 1995, 2002; OECD, 1997b). Efforts have focused on reforming
the higher education system and developing programs and institutions,
mostly managed through the National Council for Science and Technology
(CONACyT), that use federal funds and grants from international development
organizations to support collaboration between academic institutions
and firms.
The core of the reform of the higher education system in the early 1990s
was a shift of emphasis from planning to evaluation as the main criteria
for regulating the system (Casas & Luna, 1997; Kent & De Vries
2002). This measure was an indirect attempt to stimulate university-industry
collaboration through two mechanisms. First, emphasis on evaluation affected
the criteria on which governmental funds were allocated among public
universities. Increasingly, government policies have tied the release
of research funds to the university, to its development of projects useful
for industry (Arocena & Sutz, 1999; Luna, 1997a). Second, through
this action, the government has forced universities to seek external
sources of income, and thereby encouraged them to carry out research
work financed by industry (Luna, 1997a).
These efforts have been complemented by the creation of mechanisms, mostly
programs and institutions within CONACyT and other branches of the government,
which have directly or indirectly supported the collaboration between
the academic and productive sectors. Within these programs, collaboration
has usually been defined as the fomentation of research alliances with
the aim of developing or improving products and processes, as well as
providing specialized technological services to address the needs of
firms.
Outcomes
The academic sector has shown some responsiveness to stimuli intended
to foster university-industry collaboration, and has gradually overcome
ideological barriers against cooperating with industry that prevailed
during the 1960s and 1970s (de Gortari, 1997). Within some universities,
a growing interest in collaboration has been manifested through the
creation of departments aimed at supporting technological programs,
a review of the normative framework that regulates consulting and services
between academicians and industry, and the creation of committees in
charge of the operation of projects with industry. This has been the
case, not only for the National Autonomous University of Mexico (UNAM),
which has the longest tradition of industry collaboration, but also
for other large federal and state universities that have introduced
these type of institutional changes since the early 1990s, including
the Autonomous Metropolitan University (UAM), and the Autonomous University
of Nuevo Leon (Luna, 1997b, 2001). In general, the last twenty years
have seen an increase in university-founded organizations intended
to foster and manage relations with firms in a much more institutionalized
way than before (Arocena & Sutz, 1999; Casas, 1997, 2001; Gortari,
1997).
Assessments of the collaborative programs that have been implemented,
however, make it clear that industry participates infrequently, and that
mechanisms to foster university-industry relations have been largely
unsuccessful due to both a lack of demand and a lack of scope. Research
on these programs has typically consisted of a collection of individual
cases in which the criteria for success is based on the completion of
specific projects. Information gathered through these efforts, however,
is not systematic and is generally very diverse in scope, resulting in
minimum utility for larger scale analysis (e.g., Asociación Nacional
de Universidades y Institutos de Educación Superior (ANUIES),
1999; CONACyT, 2000). When individual programs have been successful and
have been able to contribute to increasing the technological capabilities
of specific firms, however, they have had limited or no impact beyond
the immediate relationship (Sutz, 2000). Unsuccessful stories have generally
not been investigated or documented.
According to Sutz (2000):
These micro-strengths are detected because they produce an innovation:
they are by definition technically successful. Their contribution to
the social accumulation of knowledge must, however, be analyzed case
by case. Many times, even if the solutions found could be easily expanded
to a whole industry, it does not trespass the walls of the firm participating
in the experience. The reasons behind the social weakness of strong
technical successes are related to the inability of the actors involved
to produce expanding virtuous circles on their own (p. 283).
Another aspect of the drive
for university-industry collaboration that has generally not been considered
is the potential
for deleterious consequences
above and beyond the intended results. The mechanisms implemented to
increase the participation of the private sector in funding R&D activities
has induced universities to be more willing to collaborate with industry,
increasing the number of business consulting missions they perform. It
has also, however, induced them to reduce the amount of basic research
they carry out (Casas & Luna 1997; Katz 2000). As such, the new mechanisms
for the distribution of research funds may have potentially negative
effects in the long term.
The transference of knowledge through the absorption of highly trained
individuals by industry has not received a great deal of attention in
the case of Mexico. Evidence strongly suggests, however, that highly
skilled manpower is sub-utilized by Mexican industry. In a historical
review of the contribution of universities to the Mexican development
process, Lorey (1993) argued that until the late 1950s, the expanding
industrial and commercial sectors and the growing government apparatus
easily absorbed the bulk of the universities' production of professionals.
Demand for a steady supply of scarce professionals was reflected in high
wages for professionals in both public and private sectors. After the
1950s, however, there was a decline in the ability of the economy to
produce jobs, and a growing majority of students with aspirations to
professional work and status could not be employed as professionals.
Lorey sustains that since then, the Mexican government has played the
role of "employer of last resort" of highly trained manpower,
and attributes these results to the poor innovative performance of industry:
...the Mexican economy did not
forge an industrial plant characterized by innovation and competitiveness
in the world
market and did not create
an independent capital-goods and research and development infrastructure.
Without innovations in the machinery used in manufacturing or an increase
in expenditure for research and development, the education and employment
of professionals could undergo no dramatic structural change. These factors
had the greatest impact on professionals trained in engineering, business,
and the sciences" (pp. 168-169).
Data support Lorey's characterization
of the government as an "employer
of last resort." In 2000, only 19 percent of highly trained human
resources working in research and development activities in Mexico worked
in a position related to the productive sector. Forty-four percent, on
the other hand, worked for the government. In South Korea, another late
industrializing country, 68 percent of these human resources are involved
in the productive sector (CONACyT, 2001; Valenti, Varela & Castillo,
2000).
A recent study conducted by the Economic Commission for Latin America
and the Caribbean (ECLAC) found that Mexico's inability to absorb increasing
supplies of highly qualified technical and professional workers, even
during relatively high-growth periods, is representative of similar patterns
across Latin America (ECLAC, 2002). The study documented a trend away
from salaried positions in industry for highly qualified workers and
an increase of concentration in lower-paying tertiary activities, largely
in services. In 2000, 58 percent of highly skilled Mexican workers, defined
as having technological or professional training, were employed by the
government, or in social, community, and personal services. Twenty-three
percent were employed in the commerce, energy, transportation, communications,
finance, and insurance sectors. Only 19 percent were working in agriculture,
mining, industry and construction. The 58 percent of skilled workers
concentrated in governmental, social, community and personal services
were on the average paid at the lowest level, 6.4 times the level of
poverty. This compares to 11.3 times the level of poverty in agriculture,
mining, industry and construction, and 13.7 times the poverty level in
financial services and the insurance sector.
These failures to foment productive university-industry collaboration
in Mexico have largely been explained by the low intensity and lack of
coordination of the relations between universities, the government, and
firms, as well as through critiques of each sector (Casas, 2001; Casas & Luna,
1997). Criticisms of Mexican universities have stressed the low quality
of human resources produced by the universities, a small academic scientific
community, a small number of graduate programs offered, a lack of funding,
scarce production of scientific and technical industry-relevant knowledge,
and rigid and bureaucratic structures (Castaños-Lomnitz, Didriksson & Newson,
1998; National Science Foundation, 2000; Valenti, Varela & Castillo,
2000; World Bank 2000).
So far, however, more than the inadequacy of knowledge produced in universities
and the lack of coordination among actors that promote collaboration,
the main constraint to developing linkages with industry may involve
the increased reliance by domestic firms on external sources of technology
as a response to trade liberalization, market deregulation, and privatization
of economic activities. The following section reviews this deintensification
of the use of local engineering, highly qualified manpower, and technological
capabilities by Mexican firms since the mid-1980s (Katz, 2001).
Industry and knowledge in Mexico
Mexico's modern economic history is typically divided into two periods:
the import-substi-tution industrialization model and the export-oriented
model.
From import-substitution
to export-oriented industrialization
Prior to the 1980s, the Mexican government carried out an economic policy,
known as Import-Substitution Industrialization (ISI), that focused on
the shielding of Mexican industry from external competition with the
goal of developing upstart industries into productive sectors capable
of substituting domestically produced commodities for imported non-durables.
In the early 1980s, the Mexican government abandoned this strategy and
adopted a different path to economic development. The new model implemented
was constructed on the premise that within a market-oriented production
system, export performance -particularly of manufactured goods- is positively
associated with economic growth (Balassa, 1981; Srinivasan, 1985; World
Bank, 1987). It also assumes that state interventions, as in the case
of ISI, result in market distortions, high economic and social costs,
and an overall failure in most developing countries linked to these policies
since the 1960s. Export-oriented industrialization (EOI) was a significant
aspect of the so-called Washington Consensus (Williamson, 1990), a set
of policy and economic reforms implemented in Latin America with the
support of the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund.
The implementation of changes in industrial and R&D policies within
the EOI strategy are particularly relevant to understanding the economic
environment in which firms operate in Mexico. The implementation of the
EOI strategy brought with it drastic reductions in trade barriers, domestic
and external financial liberalization, a minimalist role for the state,
and restrictive monetary and fiscal policies. The assumption behind this
strategy was that macroeconomic policies aimed at generating a market-friendly
environment would induce sectoral growth and development. As a consequence,
the domestic industrial policy from the ISI period that consisted of
price controls, subsidies, state intervention,
and direct state ownership in firms and sectoral programs, was abolished
in favor of "neutral policies" that
treat all firms and sectors equally and avoid any form of selection and
subsidies (Dussel Peters, 2000).
During the ISI years a large number of public R&D and engineering
centers emerged in Mexico. Public agencies took an active role during
these years in training human resources, designing and financing large-production
facilities, and developing the national scientific and technological
infrastructure (Amsden, 2001; Cimoli, 2000). Despite these efforts, a
significant flow of innovation and knowledge development from these institutions
failed to reach the private sector. According to Katz (2001), through
the ISI period, the Mexican R&D system, as in the rest of the Latin
America, was "highly fragmented in nature, lacking in sense of purpose
and depth. In the final analysis, it failed to serve as the true 'engine'
for growth in the domestic environment" (p. 6).
In shifting to the EOI model, planners sought to spur increases in the
competitiveness of Mexican firms by supporting increased R&D expenditures.
Institutionally, an attempt was also made to provide for adequate protection
of intellectual property rights in order to stimulate knowledge creation.
Intellectual property rights have been strengthened through changes in
patent law, which now allows the registration of patents in fields such
as pharmaceutical products, genetics, and software. Property rights on
natural resources, such as timber and water rights, have been deepened
and consolidated (Cimoli, 2000).
In practice, public policy in the field of R&D has shifted from supporting
public R&D conducted in labs, institutes, and universities, to financing
firms in order for them to search for cheaper and better technology providers
(Katz, 2001). Funds for R&D, however, have not increased substantially
in the last decade, and the R&D system remains largely uncoordinated
and under-funded (ECLAC, 2002).
The effect of structural reforms
on the creation of indigenous knowledge
Although the impact of adapting the new model for economic development
in Mexico has not been fully assessed, knowledge gaps do not seem to
be getting any smaller. While the modernization of plants and equipment
has, in some cases, resulted in improved technological performance, the
ability of the vast majority of Mexican firms to generate technological
knowledge has diminished as a consequence of the recent trade liberalization
and market deregulation efforts. This, in turn, has hampered the productive
sector's ability to develop linkages with other firms and domestic institutions
(Casas, 1997; Cimoli & De la Mothe, 2001; Dussel Peters, 2000).
According to Dussel Peters (2000), transnational companies (TNC) have
been relatively successful in integrating part of Mexico's economy into
the North American market. Economic liberalization has opened the door
for Mexican affiliates of TNCs, particularly in the automobile and electronics
industries, to benefit from investment, modernization efforts, and the
intensification of already existing intrafirm and intraindustry linkages.
Most of this integration, however, has occurred in relatively low value-added,
capital-intensive activities. Apart from these TNCs, however, the large
majority of firms do not possess the know-how to close knowledge gaps
that would allow them to integrate themselves into global commodity chains
and networks.
Katz (2001) identifies the following changes in the productive sector
in Mexico caused by the structural reform of the last two decades:
1) Trade liberalization has made imported capital goods cheaper than
before. Hence, firms have substituted inexpensive imported capital goods
for locally produced equipment and 'in house' engineering efforts aimed
at expanding the life cycle of capital equipment. As a consequence, the
local capital goods industry has suffered a major setback and engineering
departments of many industrial firms have stagnated.
2) The privatization of state enterprises in areas such as energy production
and telecommunication services has also led to the shuttering of local
R&D and engineering departments. These formerly state-owned enterprises,
now operated by subsidiaries of large enterprises from advanced economies,
are modernizing the domestic infrastructure on the basis of imported
capital equipment and engineering know-how that comes primarily from
abroad.
3) Subsidiaries have also reduced 'adaptive' engineering efforts that
are no longer needed since they have now become part of a global network
in which 'worldwide standard designs' are being produced. Industrial
firms have reduced 'in house' design capabilities as they now import
parts and components and employ 'on line' foreign engineering services.
According to Katz (2001):
Both in the case of the privatization of state enterprises and in the
expansion of domestically owned conglomerates in the resources processing
industries, the erection of new production capacity closer to the international
technological frontier has occurred on the basis of imported machinery
and equipment. In such cases, we find that we are moving towards technologically
more complex economies but simultaneously becoming less intensive in
the use of local engineering and technological capabilities. Human
capital ... has become obsolete and is being replaced by imported machines
'embodying' more contemporary production techniques. A similar process
would appear to be taking place in the case of domestic subsidiaries
of large transnational corporations were the need for adaptive technological
efforts seems to be much less significant today than decades before
(p. 17).
What does this mean for university-industry linkages? Generally, firms
in Mexico seem to be less interested in conducting or collaborating in
joint R&D activities. Those who have successfully increased their
technological capabilities appear to have largely done so through forging
or intensifying already existing links with firms and academic institutions
abroad (Cimoli & De la Mothe, 2001). Both of these phenomena, however,
raise questions about the role of the Mexican university as a collaborator
with industry in the innovation process.
Challenges for the future
The picture that has emerged in recent years, therefore, is one in which
universities are being prodded strongly to operate in a manner more
congruent with the demands of the market economy. Their future, particularly
in terms of the availability of funds for research, seems increasingly
dependent on the ability to adapt to the needs of the productive sector.
Industry, on the other hand, is responding to a new macro economic
environment by following a pattern of acquisition and development of
technological knowledge in which the vast majority of firms have increased
their dependence on external sources of knowledge and reduced interaction
with local institutions. An elite group of firms, largely affiliates
of transnational corporations, has developed linkages abroad through
their integration with parent companies.
Thus, the academic and productive sectors in Mexico appear to be moving
in different directions. The strategy of the Mexican government to bring
these two paths together, as described above, remains focused on stimulating
innovative performance among firms through market mechanisms. From this
perspective, the university can play a fundamental role in developing
the technological innovations and technologies that power regional economic
growth. Evidence from recent analyses, however, cast doubt upon the likelihood
that this linearprocess will bring universities and industry together
in a manner that impacts innovation processes meaningfully, despite initiatives
that encourage collaboration.
An alternative conceptualization of institutional roles in the innovation
and development process can be found in National Innovation Systems (NIS)
approaches. These approaches, which conceptualize innovation as the result
of interactions between the firm and other institutions, such as universities,
were initially utilized to understand university-industry collaborations
in advanced industrialized economies. NIS perspectives have also been
applied in the context of developing economies. The next section reviews
these approaches and discusses their viability for the case of Mexico.
National Innovation Systems (NIS)
The National Innovation System's approach, with pioneering works by Freeman
(1987), Lundvall (1993), and Nelson (1993), among others, has emerged
as a central perspective for understanding university-industry relations
and the technical innovation process in developed economies. Although
there is no single accepted definition, most conceptualizations of a
NIS build on the following assumptions hold that: 1) knowledge and innovation
are the key forces determining the competitiveness of firms and countries;
2) innovation and technical progress are the result of a complex set
of relationships among actors producing, distributing and applying various
kinds of knowledge; and 3) the innovative performance of an economy depends
to a large extent on how these actors relate to each other as elements
of a collective system of knowledge creation and use. Such systems, frequently
referred to as national innovation systems, are primarily -although not
exclusively- composed of enterprises, universities, and research institutes
(Nelson, 1993). According to the NIS view, policy-making should be directed
at encouraging the development of linkages among these actors to enhance
a nation's competitive performance (OECD, 1999). In the following discussion,
the term "national innovation systems approach" (NIS) will
be used to refer to this analytical approach, whereas the term "innovation
system(s)" will refer to the actual system composed of different
actors that intervene directly or indirectly in the generation of technological
innovations in a country.
Developed and diffused primarily by academicians, the NIS approach and
its strong policy-oriented nature has appealed to policy-makers. Within
OECD countries, it has been generally acknowledged that R&D policies
are country-specific and path-dependent, and that they tend to be more
effectively managed with the guidance of a system perspective (OECD,
1997). In practice, the NIS approach has provided an analytical framework
suitable to conduct concrete empirical and comparative analyses for the
design of specific policies in the fields of R&D and innovation in
economically advanced countries. Specific policy recommendations that
stem from the NIS perspective have generally been developed through analyses
based on the collection of information at the firm level, through case
studies or indicators and surveys that help to explain aggregate phenomena.
NIS and university-industry collaboration
Research from an NIS perspective has focused on the ways in which university
science contributes to technical advance in industry, and the ways
in which technical advance in industry contributes to fundamental understanding
(Nelson, 1994). These entities are viewed as interrelated, and the
distinction between academic science and technological advance in industry
is blurred. This view emphasizes the need of coordinated government
intervention to clear the channels through which knowledge flows between
the productive and academic sectors in order to strengthen the networks
that support technological innovation (OECD, 1999). It tells little,
however, about the specific role of the university in the innovative
process. According to Florida and Cohen (1999), this view "fail[s]
to fully grasp the objective function of the university, the intricate
and complex ways in which the university is embedded within economy
and society, and the full nature of the tensions thereby generated" (p.
592).
While NIS approaches have been more successful in incorporating the influences
of culture and national institutional infrastructure into their analysis,
they have not raised the question of how and to what degree university-industry
collaboration efforts fit into different stages of the development process.
In effect, NIS approaches have been used as a reference framework to
design policies aiming at intensifying university-industry collaboration
(OECD, 1999). While this approach has been relatively uncontroversial
in the advanced industrial contexts of Western Europe and the United
States, its relevancy to developing economies like Mexico is not as clear.
NIS and developing countries
Perhaps the main drawback of the NIS approach in a country like Mexico
is that it provides little insight on how to create an innovation system
that effectively incorporates national actors, such as universities.
While NIS systems have effectively been incorporated into analysis
of strong diversified economic systems with well developed institutional
and infrastructure support of innovation activities, the relevancy
for system building remains undemonstrated (Lundvall, Johnson, Andersen & Dalum,
2001).
In more developed OECD countries, innovation systems have been evolving
over time as countries have industrialized. Prior to the 1980s, the role
of science for technological innovation was traditionally mediated through
various channels, including labor mobility and informal relations between
the academic and productive sectors. It was only in the 1980s that policy
makers in these countries recognized the need for purposeful coordination
to improve overall domestic innovative performance. This came to be,
at least partially, as a response to the challenges imposed by specific
events such as the successful emergence of Japan as a super power in
the international market, the rapid development and dissemination of
information and communications technology, and the lagged growth of their
own productivity despite large investments in new technologies (Shulin
1999). In these cases of developed economies, different combinations
of government intervention and market mechanisms were applied at both
the national and the firm level to forge national systems of innovation.
Most researchers involved in the development of the NIS approach, and
policymakers who have been their main audience, have been specifically
interested in the structure and dynamics of national systems. This fact
reflects a belief that the innovative prowess of national firms is determined
to a considerable extent by government policies and by the functioning
of domestic institutions, which in turn influence factors such as intellectual
property rights, standards, capital and labor market regulations, and
contract laws. The possibility, however, must be considered that the
concept of a national system of innovation is becoming less meaningful
as cross-border linkages and information flows increase along with the
internationalization of corporate R&D (Patel & Pavitt, 1998).
In the case of Latin American economies, the impact of trade liberalization
and of deregulation and privatization of economic activities that has
taken place over the last two decades has resulted in increased interconnectedness
with institutions and firms abroad and less responsiveness to domestic
incentives for collaboration. Mexico is a prime example of this phenomenon.
According to Katz (2001), "...the change in the global incentive
regime has blurred the limits and national identity of the various local
innovation systems, enhancing the role played by external firms, institutions
and sourcesof know-how" (p. 18). If the NIS perspective is to be
used to analyze developing economies, more research on the impact of
globalization processes on system building in developing countries and
the relationships between globalization and national-local systems is
needed.
Another important criticism of the NIS approach is, paradoxically, its
lack of system-level explanatory analysis. Typically, scholars have focused
on the roles of specific actors and the impact of specific policies and
institutions, but have not provided system-level descriptions of the
national systems' structural dynamics of performance. This has limited
their ability to develop comparisons with non-OECD countries or regions
that have very different starting conditions or to develop alternative
system structures to accomplish technological innovation. The NIS approach
has yet to explore the possibility that alternative system structures
may be necessary to achieve technological innovation in economies with
very different starting conditions, including but not limited to central
planning and functionally specialized organizations, for example (Liu & White,
2001).
So far, NIS approaches have not been readily adapted to the characteristics
of a late-industrializing country like Mexico, rendering the NIS reference
framework insufficient to understand and encourage collaborative patterns
between the academic and productive sectors in these contexts. The next
section reviews alternative perspectives in the context of experiences
of both developed and developing countries.
Universities and industry:
lessons from experience
This section turns to experiences of university-industry collaboration
in developed economies, and in late-industrializing countries in East
Asia, particularly elements of these experiences that potentially serve
to clarify the nature of collaboration between the academic and industrial
sectors in Mexico.
Diversity of university-industry collaborative patterns
Although there is a common trend to encourage university-industry collaboration
in advanced economies, the direct contribution of universities to industrial
development varies among countries. Japan and the United States for example,
contain similar industries and face many of the same challenges of harnessing
scientific research for purposes of technological innovation. Yet relations
between industrial firms and universities have developed quite differently
in these countries. American universities have elaborated a host of formal
arrangements for conducting industry-sponsored research and transferring
technology to commercial applications (Feller, 1999; Rahm, Krikland & Bozeman,
2000). These types of formal arrangements are relatively rare in Japan.
Japanese industry has instead met many of its technological needs through
the establishment of central research institutes, while maintaining strong
networks of tacit, informal relationships with academic scientists. In
fact, Japanese companies seeking research partners have at times found
it easier to form agreements with American universities (Pechter & Kakinuma;
Peck & Tamura 1976; Rahm, Krikland and Bozeman 2000).
University-industry collaboration experiences in developed economies
show that linkages between academy and industry can take many forms,
be initiated in a number of ways, and take place on different scales.
The specific form of collaboration developed in a country seems to be
heavily influenced by the institutional framework for technological innovation,
the level of technological development reached by the productive sector,
and cultural and historical factors. Parker (1991) shows that great a
variety of mechanisms to induce collaboration have been developed through
the years. While there does not seem to be a consensus on which approaches
are especially effective under a wide range of circumstances, it does
seem clear that collaboration is not inherently natural for either the
university or industry, and finding the adequate mechanisms is often
the result of trial and error processes.
University in late industrialization experiences in East Asia
The experiences of countries like South Korea, Taiwan and Singapore provide
useful insights to understand the role of universities during the "catch
up" process. Evidence from these countries shows that a sustainable
pace of technological development can be attained despite engaging in
relatively little basic research and establishing few university-industry
linkages (Kim, 1997; Lall, 1990). In these countries, university research
has frequently been described as inadequate, insufficient, or de-linked
from the needs of the domestic industry (Berger & Lester, 1997; Kim,
1997; Peck & Tamura, 1976). Economic performance has been attained
through intense and coordinated efforts at acquiring advanced technologies
from industrialized economies. Thus, technological prowess in these countries
is not founded on conventional approaches to innovation and R&D,
but instead, on a well developed system of management of technological
diffusion that has evolved dynamically in the last decades in response
to changes in industry (Mathews, 1999). These countries have aggressively
encouraged R&D activities to solve individual problems with applications,
and basic science has been a lower priority. Given the inadequacy of
university research to meet the specific needs of a "late-comer" industrial
sector, governments, have made public R&D institutes the backbone
of advances in R&D (Berger & Lester, 1997; Hobday, 1995; Kim,
1997).
To what extent the lack of strong ties between university and industry
impedes these economies systems from moving up the value-chain in global
production is an open question. Its answer seems to be closely related
to the characteristics of the R&D needed by domestic industry. Forbes
and Wield (2000) argue that, given the fact that most R&D conducted
in these countries is more development than research, a very new conceptualization
of R&D is required in countries that perform as "technology
followers." Accordingly:
Rather than pushing out the technology frontier... innovation tasks
in followers should aim to approach and follow the frontier as efficiently
as possible, with the objective to move the firm up the value-chain of
global production by increasing productivity and making higher value
products. That the future technology frontier is known to followers reduces
uncertainty involved in innovation, [and] makes the innovative task different
[from developed economies] (p.1096).
This form of R&D takes place primarily within the firm. The implication
this conceptualization has on the role of basic research generated in
developing countries' universities, however, has been virtually unexplored
in the literature.
Evidence from these East Asian economies shows that as industrial progress
takes place, there is still a crucial need for university participation,
but rather in an indirect form, through the formation of manpower. In
South Korea, for example, the lack of development in university research
has been perceived as a bottleneck for industrial performance because
it inhibits the development of research abilities in students that later
move to the labor market (Kim, 1997). More than the research results,
the main benefit from collaboration seems to be exposing students to
applied research, which familiarizes them with the private sector and
increases their capabilities of succeeding in this sector (Berger & Lester,
1997; Parker, 1991).
University research as an engine
of economic development
Thus, the vision of university research as an engine of economic development
is rather simplistic. East Asian economies have found that although there
are important benefits from stimulating direct interaction between university
and industry, the university has been far from playing the role of an "engine" for
industrial development. Evidence from developed countries support this
view. Florida and Cohen (1999) argue that:
The role of the university in
economic development has captured the fancy of business leaders, policy-makers,
and academics
as they have
looked at the examples of technology-based regions like Silicon Valley
and the Route 128 region surrounding Boston and Cambridge. They have
concluded that the university has played a fundamental role in developing
the technological innovations and technologies that power those regional
economic models. A theory of sorts has been handed down based mainly
on anecdotes and so-called success stories of the university as "engine" of
regional economic development...what appears to matter here -and what
it is too often neglected in policy circles- is the ability of a region
to absorb the science, innovation and technologies which universities
generate (pp.604-605).
University-industry collaboration, therefore is not necessarily a cause
of high levels of competitiveness in industry but instead the result
of a combination of a variety of interconnected local elements, including
adequate mechanisms to enhance collaboration, a local research community
well connected with the international science community, a significant
amount of technology-based firms, and a domestic R&D system focused
on the demands of the productive sector, among other factors. Thus, it
becomes clear that it is the pace of technological change, more than
government incentives, which puts universities in the position of driving
industrial growth (Branscomb, Kodama, & Florida, 1999).
Conclusions
It is widely recognized by policy-makers and researchers that if Mexico
is to adopt a path for economic development characterized by the production
of high value goods, it has to increase its ability to acquire, transform,
and generate technological knowledge. In this context, public interest
has increasingly perceived the university as a crucial source of new
skills, knowledge and ideas. This has placed the research university
in the role of something akin to the fuel that drives the "engine" of
development.
There are two assumptions behind this expectation: first, that there
is a linear pathway from university investigation to commercial innovation
to regional development and widening networks of innovation; second that
if institutional structures and relationships can be transformed to replicate
those observed in advanced industrialized nations, innovation and expanding
innovatory networks will necessarily follow.
These assumptions, however, may be of limited usefulness for the case
of Mexico, and at least three important elements need to be considered
while trying to conceptualize the role of university-industry collaboration
in Mexico. First, although collaboration brings important benefits to
the parties involved, it is not inherently natural for either the university
or industry, and finding policies that encourage the development of linkages
between the academic and productive sector seems to be the result of
a trial and error process.
Second, collaboration is not a static concept. Instead it evolves over
time and is influenced by cultural and institutional factors that also
influence the industrial development process. More research is needed
to understand how and to what degree university-industry collaboration
efforts fit into different stages of the development process of particular
economies.
Third, the vision of university research as an engine of economic development
is rather simplistic. More than a cause of potentially high levels of
competitiveness in industry, university-industry collaboration is more
the result of a combination of a variety of interconnected local elements.
Hence, rather than being a final recommendation, university-industry
collaboration in the Mexican context, is the beginning of a little explored
research path that demands innovation in policy making and reflective
thinking.
References
AMSDEN, A. (1989). Asia's next gigant: South Korea and late industrialization.
New York, Oxford University Press.
AMSDEN, A. (2001). The rise of the rest: Challenges to the west from
late-industrializing economies. Oxford, Oxford University Press.
ANUIES (1999). Casos exitosos de vinculacion universidad-empresa. Memorias
del Foro Nacional de Vinculacion de las Instituciones de Educación
con el sector productivo, México, Asociación Nacional de
Universidades e Instituciones de Educación Superior (Anuies).
ARCHIBUGI D. and L. B. Lundvall (eds.) (2001). The globalizing learning
economy. Oxford, Oxford University Press.
AROCENA, R. & Sutz, J. (2001). "Changing knowledge production
and Latin American universities", Research Policy, 30.
BALASSA, B. (1989). Comparative advantage, trade policy and economic
development. New York, New York University Press.
BERGER S. and R.K. Lester (eds.) (1997). Made by Hong Kong. Oxford, Oxford
University Press.
CAPDEVIELLE M., J.M. Corona and C. Hernandez (2000). "Production
system and technological patterns", in Cimoli M. (ed.) Developing
innovation systems: Mexico in a global context. London, Continuum pp
57-80.
CASAS R. (ed.) (2001). La formación de redes de conocimiento:
Una perspectiva regional desde México, Rubí (Barcelona),
Anthropos, México, Instituto de Investigaciones Sociales, UNAM.
CASAS R. (1997). "El gobierno: hacia un nuevo paradigma de política
para la vinculación", in Casas, R. and Luna M. (eds.) Gobierno,
academia y empresas en México: Hacia una nueva configuración
de relaciones, México, Plaza y Valdés and Instituto de
Investigaciones Sociales, Universidad Autónoma de México.
CASAS, R. De Gortari, R., and Luna, M. (2000). "University, Knowledge
Production and Collaborative Patterns with Industry", in Cimoli,
M. (ed.) Developing innovation systems: México in a global context.
London and New York: Continuum.
CASAS, R. and De Gortari, R. (1997). "La vinculación en la
UNAM: Hacia una nueva cultura académica basada en la empresarialidad",
in Casas, R. and Luna M. (eds.) Gobierno, academia y empresas en México:
Hacia una nueva configuración de relaciones, Mexico, Plaza y Valdés
and Instituto de Investigaciones Sociales, Universidad Autónoma
de México.
CASAS, R. and Luna M. (eds.) (1997). Gobierno, academia y empresas en
México: Hacia una nueva configuración de relaciones, México,
Plaza y Valdés and Instituto de Investigaciones Sociales, Universidad
Autónoma de México.
CASTAÑOS-Lomnitz, A. Didriksson, and J. Newson (1998). "Reshaping
the educational agendas of Mexican universities: The impact of NAFTA".
In Currie J. and J. Newson (eds.). Universities and globalization: Critical
perspectives. Thousand Oaks, Calif., Sage Publications.
CIMOLI M. (1999). "La relación universidad-empresa en el
sistema mexicano de innovación", in Casos Exitosos de Vinculacion
Universidad Empresa. Memorias del Foro Nacional de Vinculación
de las Instituciones de Educación con el Sector Productivo: Casos
Exitosos. México, Asociación Nacional de Universidades
e Institutos de Educación Superior.
CIMOLI, M. (1998). National systems of innovation: a note of technological
asymmetries and catching-up perspectives, International Institute for
Applied Systems. Interim Report IR-98-030/June.
CIMOLI, M. & De la Mothe, J. (2001). "Technology, growth and
development", in De la Mothe J. (ed.) Science, technology and Governance,
London, Continuum.
CONACyT (2001). Programa Nacional de ciencia y tecnología 2001-2006.
Consejo Nacional de Ciencia y Tecnología. Retrieved on July 24,
2002 from www.conacyt.mx.
CONACyT (2000). Casos de éxito de empresas apoyadas por la dirección
adjunta de modernización tecnológica. Retrieved on September
14, 2001 from http://www.conacyt.mx.
CONACyT (1995). Programa de Ciencia y Tecnología. Retrieved on
July 24, 2002 from www.conacyt.mx.
CORREA M. C. (2000). "University-enterprise linkages in the area
of biotechnology", in Lopez-Martinez R. E. and A. Piccaluga (eds.)
Knowledge flows in national systems of innovation, Northampton, Edward
Elgar.
DUSSEL Peters, E. (2000). Polarizing Mexico: The impact of liberalization
strategy, London, Lynne Rienner Publishers.
ECLAC (2001). Panorama social de América Latina 2001-2002. Retrieved
on October 23, 2002 from http://www.eclac.cl.
EDQUIST, C. (2001). "Innovation policy: A system approach",
in Archibugi Daniele and Bengt-Åke Lundvall (eds.). The globalizing
learning economy Oxford University Press.
ERNST, D. and B.-Å. Lundvall (1997). Information technology in
the learning economy: Challenges for developing countries, DRUID Working
Paper, Aalbort, Department of Business Studies.
FELLER, I. (1999). "The American university system as a performer
of basic and applied research", in L.M. Branscomb, F. Kodama, & R.
Florida (Eds.). Industrializing knowledge: University-industry linkages
in Japan and the United States (pp. 65-101). Cambridge, MIT Press.
FLORIDA, R., & Cohen, W.M. (1999). "Engine or infrastructure?
The university role in economic development", in L.M. Branscomb,
F. Kodama, & R. Florida (Eds.). Industrializing knowledge: University-industry
linkages in Japan and the United States (pp. 589-610). Cambridge, MIT
Press.
FREEMAN C. and L. Soete (2000). The economics of industrial innovation,
Cambridge, The MIT Press, 3rd edition.
FREEMAN, C. (1987). Technology policy and economic performance: Lessons
from Japan, London, Printer.
GEUNA, A. (1999). The economics of knowledge production: Funding and
the structure of university research, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
GORTARI, R. (2001). "Las universidades publicas estatales: Estrategias
y factores de colaboración con las empresas", in Casas R.
(Ed.). La formación de redes de conocimiento, Barcelona, Anthropos;
Instituto de Investigaciones Sociales, UNAM.
------- (1997). "Los académicos: de la producción
a la comercialización del conocimiento", in Casas, R. & Luna
M. (Eds.). Gobierno, academia y empresas en México: Hacia una
nueva configuración de relaciones, México, Plaza y Valdés
e Instituto de Investigaciones Sociales, Universidad Autónoma
de México.
HOBDAY, M. (1995). Innovation in East Asia,Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
KATZ, J. (2001). "Structural reforms and technological behavior:
The sources and nature of technological change in Latin America in the
1990s". Research Policy, 30.
KENT, R, y W. De Vries (2002). Políticas federales en la educación
superior mexicana, Retrieved on July 20, 2002 from http://www.nyu.edu/iesp/aiheps.
KIM, L. (1997). Imitation to innovation: The dynamics of Korea's Technological
Learning, Boston, Harvard Business School Press.
KODAMA, F., & Branscomb, L.M. (1999). "University research as
an engine for growth: How realistic is the vision?", in L.M. Branscomb
et al. (Eds.). Industrializing knowledge: University-industry linkages
in Japan and the United States, Cambridge, MIT Press.
LALL, S. (1990). Building industrial competitiveness in developing countries,
Paris, OECD.
LIU, X. & S. White (2001). "Comparing innovation systems: A
framework and application to China's transitional context", Research
Policy 304.
LOREY, D.E. (1993). The university system and economic development in
Mexico since 1929, Stanford, Stanford University Press.
LUNA, M. (1997a). "Modelos de coordinación entre el gobierno,
el sector privado y los académicos", in Casas, R. and Luna
M. (Eds.). Gobierno, academia y empresas en México: Hacia una
nueva configuración de relaciones, México, Plaza y Valdés
Instituto de Investigaciones Sociales, Universidad Autónoma de
México.
------ (1997b). "Panorama de vinculación en la Universidad
Autónoma Metropolitana", in Casas R. (Ed.) (2001). La formación
de redes de conocimiento: Una perspectiva regional desde México.
Barcelona, Anthropos; Instituto de Investigaciones Sociales, UNAM.
LIU, X. a S. White (2001). "Comparing innovation systems: A framework
and application to China's transitional context", Research Policy
30.
LUNDVALL, B-Å (2002). The university in the learning economy, DRUID
Working Paper 02-06. Aalbort, Department of Business Studies.
---------- (2001). "Innovation policy in the globalizing learning
economy", in D. Archibugi & B-Å Lundvall (Eds.). The globalizing
learning economy, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
-----------, et al (2001). "National systems of production, innovation
and competence building", Paper presented at the Nelson and Winter
DRUID Summer Conference, Aalborg, Congress Center, Aalborg, Denmark,
June 12-15.
--------- (1992) (Ed.). National systems of innovation: Towards a theory
of innovation and interactive learning, London, Printer.
MATHEWS, J.A. (1999). "From national innovation systems to national
system of economic learning: The case of technology diffusion management
in East Asia.", Paper submitted to DRUID Summer Conference: National
Innovation Systems, Industrial Dynamics and Innovation Policy, Rebild,
Denmark June 9-12 1999.
MOROTE, E.S.& Yeager, J.L. (2000). "Higher education: The social,
political and economic driver of Mexico's future", in M.S. McMullen,
J.E. Mauch, and B. Donnorummo (Eds.): The emerging markets and higher
education, New York, Routledge Falmer.
NATIONAL SCIENCE FOUNDATION (2000). Graduate education reform in Europe,
Asia and the Americas and international mobility of scientists and engineers:
Proceedings of an NSF Workshop, Retrieved on January 28, 2002 from http://www.nsf.gov/sbe/srs/nsf00318/htmstart.htm.
NEEF, D, G.A. Siesfeld, J. Cefola (eds.) (1998). The economic impact
of knowledge, Boston, Butterworth Heinemann.
NELSON, R.R. (1959). "The simple economics of R&D", American
Economic Review.
------- (1996). The sources of economic growth. Cambridge Mass.: Harvard
University Press.
------- (Ed.) (1993). National innovation systems: A comparative analysis,
New York, Oxford University Press.
OECD (1996). The knowledge-based economy, Paris, OECD.
-----(1997a). National innovation systems, Paris, OECD.
-----(1997b). Reviews of national policies for education: Mexico, higher
education, Paris, OECD.
-----(1999). Managing national innovation systems, Paris, OECD.
PATEL, T. & K. Pavitt (1998). National systems of innovation under
strain: The internationalization of corporate R&D. Electronic working
paper series, paper No. 22, http://www.sussex,ac,uk/spru/.
PECHTER, K. & Kakinuma S.(1999). "Coauthorship linkages between
university research and Japanese industry", in L.M. Branscomb et
al. (Eds.). Industrializing knowledge: University-industry linkages in
Japan and the United, Cambridge, MIT Press.
PECK, M.J., & Tamura, S. (1976). "Technology", in Patrick
H. and H. Rosovsky (Eds). Asia's new giant: How the Japanese economy
works, Washington D.C., The Brookings Institution.
RAHM, D. J. Kirkland & B. Bozeman (2000). University-industry R&D
collaboration in the United States, the United Kingdom and Japan, Dordrecht,
The Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
ROGOZINSKI, Jacques (1993). La privatizacion de empresas paraestatales,
México, Fondo de Cultura Económica.
RUBENSON, K. & H.G. Schuetze (2000). Transition to the knowledge
society: Policies and strategies for individual particupation and learning,
Vancouver, UBC Institute for European Studies.
SÁNCHEZ UGARTE, F., et al. (1994). La política industrial
ante la apertura, México, SECOFI Fondo de Cultura Económica.
SHULIN, Gu (1999). Implications of national innovation systems for developing
countries: Managing change and complexity in economic development, United
Nations University discussion paper series #9903.
SRINIVASAN, T.N. (1985). "Trade policy and development", in
J. Bhagwati (Ed.). Dependence and Interdependence, Cambridge, MIT Press.
SUTZ, J. (2000). "The university-industry-government relations in Latin
America", Research Policy, 29.
VALENTI,G., et al. (2000). "Human resources and competencies", in
Cimoli M. (Ed.). Developing innovation systems: Mexico in a global context,
London, Continuum.
WILLIAMSON, J. (1990). What Washington means by policy reform. In Latin American
Adjustment: How Much as happened? Washington, D.C., Ed. J. Williamson., Institute
of International Economics.
WEN, J. and S. Kibayashi (2000). "Exploring collaborative R&D network:
Somenew evidence in Japan", Research Policy, 20.
WOLFGANG, B. and J. Peters (2000). "University knowledge and innovation
activities: evidence from the German manufacturing industry", in Saviotti
P.P. and B. Nooteboom (Eds.). Technology and knowledge: From the firm to innovation
systems, Cheltenham, U.K., Edward Elgar.
WORLD BANK (2000). Higher education in developing countries: Peril and promise,
Washington, D.C., The World Bank.
------- (1999). World development report 1998/99: Knowledge for development,
New York, Oxford University Press.
------ (1994). Higher education: The lessons of experience. Washington, D.C.,
The World Bank.
------ (1987). World development report, New York, Oxford University Press.
|